Prove That the Max of Two Continuous Functions is Continuous Topology

Provides conditions for a parametric optimization problem to have continuous solutions

The maximum theorem provides conditions for the continuity of an optimized function and the set of its maximizers with respect to its parameters. The statement was first proven by Claude Berge in 1959.[1] The theorem is primarily used in mathematical economics and optimal control.

Statement of theorem [edit]

Maximum Theorem.[2] [3] [4] [5] Let X {\displaystyle X} and Θ {\displaystyle \Theta } be topological spaces, f : X × Θ R {\displaystyle f:X\times \Theta \to \mathbb {R} } be a continuous function on the product X × Θ {\displaystyle X\times \Theta } , and C : Θ X {\displaystyle C:\Theta \rightrightarrows X} be a compact-valued correspondence such that C ( θ ) {\displaystyle C(\theta )\neq \emptyset } for all θ Θ {\displaystyle \theta \in \Theta } . Define the marginal function (or value function) f : Θ R {\displaystyle f^{*}:\Theta \to \mathbb {R} } by

f ( θ ) = sup { f ( x , θ ) : x C ( θ ) } {\displaystyle f^{*}(\theta )=\sup\{f(x,\theta ):x\in C(\theta )\}}

and the set of maximizers C : Θ X {\displaystyle C^{*}:\Theta \rightrightarrows X} by

C ( θ ) = a r g max { f ( x , θ ) : x C ( θ ) } = { x C ( θ ) : f ( x , θ ) = f ( θ ) } {\displaystyle C^{*}(\theta )=\mathrm {arg} \max\{f(x,\theta ):x\in C(\theta )\}=\{x\in C(\theta ):f(x,\theta )=f^{*}(\theta )\}} .

If C {\displaystyle C} is continuous (i.e. both upper and lower hemicontinuous) at θ {\displaystyle \theta } , then f {\displaystyle f^{*}} is continuous and C {\displaystyle C^{*}} is upper hemicontinuous with nonempty and compact values. As a consequence, the sup {\displaystyle \sup } may be replaced by max {\displaystyle \max } .

Interpretation [edit]

The theorem is typically interpreted as providing conditions for a parametric optimization problem to have continuous solutions with regard to the parameter. In this case, Θ {\displaystyle \Theta } is the parameter space, f ( x , θ ) {\displaystyle f(x,\theta )} is the function to be maximized, and C ( θ ) {\displaystyle C(\theta )} gives the constraint set that f {\displaystyle f} is maximized over. Then, f ( θ ) {\displaystyle f^{*}(\theta )} is the maximized value of the function and C {\displaystyle C^{*}} is the set of points that maximize f {\displaystyle f} .

The result is that if the elements of an optimization problem are sufficiently continuous, then some, but not all, of that continuity is preserved in the solutions.

Proof [edit]

Throughout this proof we will use the term neighborhood to refer to an open set containing a particular point. We preface with a preliminary lemma, which is a general fact in the calculus of correspondences. Recall that a correspondence is closed if its graph is closed.

Lemma.[6] [7] [8] If A , B : Θ X {\displaystyle A,B:\Theta \rightrightarrows X} are correspondences, A {\displaystyle A} is upper hemicontinuous and compact-valued, and B {\displaystyle B} is closed, then A B : Θ X {\displaystyle A\cap B:\Theta \rightrightarrows X} defined by ( A B ) ( θ ) = A ( θ ) B ( θ ) {\displaystyle (A\cap B)(\theta )=A(\theta )\cap B(\theta )} is upper hemicontinuous.

Proof

Let θ Θ {\displaystyle \theta \in \Theta } , and suppose G {\displaystyle G} is an open set containing ( A B ) ( θ ) {\displaystyle (A\cap B)(\theta )} . If A ( θ ) G {\displaystyle A(\theta )\subseteq G} , then the result follows immediately. Otherwise, observe that for each x A ( θ ) G {\displaystyle x\in A(\theta )\setminus G} we have x B ( θ ) {\displaystyle x\notin B(\theta )} , and since B {\displaystyle B} is closed there is a neighborhood U x × V x {\displaystyle U_{x}\times V_{x}} of ( θ , x ) {\displaystyle (\theta ,x)} in which x B ( θ ) {\displaystyle x'\notin B(\theta ')} whenever ( θ , x ) U x × V x {\displaystyle (\theta ',x')\in U_{x}\times V_{x}} . The collection of sets { G } { V x : x A ( θ ) G } {\displaystyle \{G\}\cup \{V_{x}:x\in A(\theta )\setminus G\}} forms an open cover of the compact set A ( θ ) {\displaystyle A(\theta )} , which allows us to extract a finite subcover G , V x 1 , , V x n {\displaystyle G,V_{x_{1}},\dots ,V_{x_{n}}} . By upper hemicontinuity, there is a neighborhood U θ {\displaystyle U_{\theta }} of θ {\displaystyle \theta } such that A ( U θ ) G V x 1 V x n {\displaystyle A(U_{\theta })\subseteq G\cup V_{x_{1}}\cup \dots \cup V_{x_{n}}} . Then whenever θ U θ U x 1 U x n {\displaystyle \theta '\in U_{\theta }\cap U_{x_{1}}\cap \dots \cap U_{x_{n}}} , we have A ( θ ) G V x 1 V x n {\displaystyle A(\theta ')\subseteq G\cup V_{x_{1}}\cup \dots \cup V_{x_{n}}} , and so ( A B ) ( θ ) G {\displaystyle (A\cap B)(\theta ')\subseteq G} . This completes the proof. {\displaystyle \square }

The continuity of f {\displaystyle f^{*}} in the maximum theorem is the result of combining two independent theorems together.

Theorem 1.[9] [10] [11] If f {\displaystyle f} is upper semicontinuous and C {\displaystyle C} is upper hemicontinuous, nonempty and compact-valued, then f {\displaystyle f^{*}} is upper semicontinuous.

Proof of Theorem 1

Fix θ Θ {\displaystyle \theta \in \Theta } , and let ε > 0 {\displaystyle \varepsilon >0} be arbitrary. For each x C ( θ ) {\displaystyle x\in C(\theta )} , there exists a neighborhood U x × V x {\displaystyle U_{x}\times V_{x}} of ( θ , x ) {\displaystyle (\theta ,x)} such that whenever ( θ , x ) U x × V x {\displaystyle (\theta ',x')\in U_{x}\times V_{x}} , we have f ( x , θ ) < f ( x , θ ) + ε {\displaystyle f(x',\theta ')<f(x,\theta )+\varepsilon } . The set of neighborhoods { V x : x C ( θ ) } {\displaystyle \{V_{x}:x\in C(\theta )\}} covers C ( θ ) {\displaystyle C(\theta )} , which is compact, so V x 1 , , V x n {\displaystyle V_{x_{1}},\dots ,V_{x_{n}}} suffice. Furthermore, since C {\displaystyle C} is upper hemicontinuous, there exists a neighborhood U {\displaystyle U'} of θ {\displaystyle \theta } such that whenever θ U {\displaystyle \theta '\in U'} it follows that C ( θ ) k = 1 n V x k {\displaystyle C(\theta ')\subseteq \bigcup _{k=1}^{n}V_{x_{k}}} . Let U = U U x 1 U x n {\displaystyle U=U'\cap U_{x_{1}}\cap \dots \cap U_{x_{n}}} . Then for all θ U {\displaystyle \theta '\in U} , we have f ( x , θ ) < f ( x k , θ ) + ε {\displaystyle f(x',\theta ')<f(x_{k},\theta )+\varepsilon } for each x C ( θ ) {\displaystyle x'\in C(\theta ')} , as x V x k {\displaystyle x'\in V_{x_{k}}} for some k {\displaystyle k} . It follows that

f ( θ ) = sup x C ( θ ) f ( x , θ ) < max k = 1 , , n f ( x k , θ ) + ε f ( θ ) + ε , {\displaystyle f^{*}(\theta ')=\sup _{x'\in C(\theta ')}f(x',\theta ')<\max _{k=1,\dots ,n}f(x_{k},\theta )+\varepsilon \leq f^{*}(\theta )+\varepsilon ,}

which was desired. {\displaystyle \square }

Theorem 2.[12] [13] [14] If f {\displaystyle f} is lower semicontinuous and C {\displaystyle C} is lower hemicontinuous, then f {\displaystyle f^{*}} is lower semicontinuous.

Proof of Theorem 2

Fix θ Θ {\displaystyle \theta \in \Theta } , and let ε > 0 {\displaystyle \varepsilon >0} be arbitrary. By definition of f {\displaystyle f^{*}} , there exists x C ( θ ) {\displaystyle x\in C(\theta )} such that f ( θ ) < f ( x , θ ) + ε 2 {\displaystyle f^{*}(\theta )<f(x,\theta )+{\frac {\varepsilon }{2}}} . Now, since f {\displaystyle f} is lower semicontinuous, there exists a neighborhood U 1 × V {\displaystyle U_{1}\times V} of ( θ , x ) {\displaystyle (\theta ,x)} such that whenever ( θ , x ) U 1 × V {\displaystyle (\theta ',x')\in U_{1}\times V} we have f ( x , θ ) < f ( x , θ ) + ε 2 {\displaystyle f(x,\theta )<f(x',\theta ')+{\frac {\varepsilon }{2}}} . Observe that C ( θ ) V {\displaystyle C(\theta )\cap V\neq \emptyset } (in particular, x C ( θ ) V {\displaystyle x\in C(\theta )\cap V} ). Therefore, since C {\displaystyle C} is lower hemicontinuous, there exists a neighborhood U 2 {\displaystyle U_{2}} such that whenever θ U 2 {\displaystyle \theta '\in U_{2}} there exists x C ( θ ) V {\displaystyle x'\in C(\theta ')\cap V} . Let U = U 1 U 2 {\displaystyle U=U_{1}\cap U_{2}} . Then whenever θ U {\displaystyle \theta '\in U} there exists x C ( θ ) V {\displaystyle x'\in C(\theta ')\cap V} , which implies

f ( θ ) < f ( x , θ ) + ε 2 < f ( x , θ ) + ε f ( θ ) + ε {\displaystyle f^{*}(\theta )<f(x,\theta )+{\frac {\varepsilon }{2}}<f(x',\theta ')+\varepsilon \leq f^{*}(\theta ')+\varepsilon }

which was desired. {\displaystyle \square }

Under the hypotheses of the Maximum theorem, f {\displaystyle f^{*}} is continuous. It remains to verify that C {\displaystyle C^{*}} is an upper hemicontinuous correspondence with compact values. Let θ Θ {\displaystyle \theta \in \Theta } . To see that C ( θ ) {\displaystyle C^{*}(\theta )} is nonempty, observe that the function f θ : C ( θ ) R {\displaystyle f_{\theta }:C(\theta )\to \mathbb {R} } by f θ ( x ) = f ( x , θ ) {\displaystyle f_{\theta }(x)=f(x,\theta )} is continuous on the compact set C ( θ ) {\displaystyle C(\theta )} . The Extreme Value theorem implies that C ( θ ) {\displaystyle C^{*}(\theta )} is nonempty. In addition, since f θ {\displaystyle f_{\theta }} is continuous, it follows that C ( θ ) {\displaystyle C^{*}(\theta )} a closed subset of the compact set C ( θ ) {\displaystyle C(\theta )} , which implies C ( θ ) {\displaystyle C^{*}(\theta )} is compact. Finally, let D : Θ X {\displaystyle D:\Theta \rightrightarrows X} be defined by D ( θ ) = { x X : f ( x , θ ) = f ( θ ) } {\textstyle D(\theta )=\{x\in X:f(x,\theta )=f^{*}(\theta )\}} . Since f {\displaystyle f} is a continuous function, D {\displaystyle D} is a closed correspondence. Moreover, since C ( θ ) = C ( θ ) D ( θ ) {\displaystyle C^{*}(\theta )=C(\theta )\cap D(\theta )} , the preliminary Lemma implies that C {\displaystyle C^{*}} is upper hemicontinuous. {\displaystyle \square }

Variants and generalizations [edit]

A natural generalization from the above results gives sufficient local conditions for f {\displaystyle f^{*}} to be continuous and C {\displaystyle C^{*}} to be nonempty, compact-valued, and upper semi-continuous.

If in addition to the conditions above, f {\displaystyle f} is quasiconcave in x {\displaystyle x} for each θ {\displaystyle \theta } and C {\displaystyle C} is convex-valued, then C {\displaystyle C^{*}} is also convex-valued. If f {\displaystyle f} is strictly quasiconcave in x {\displaystyle x} for each θ {\displaystyle \theta } and C {\displaystyle C} is convex-valued, then C {\displaystyle C^{*}} is single-valued, and thus is a continuous function rather than a correspondence.

If f {\displaystyle f} is concave and C {\displaystyle C} has a convex graph, then f {\displaystyle f^{*}} is concave and C {\displaystyle C^{*}} is convex-valued. Similarly to above, if f {\displaystyle f} is strictly concave, then C {\displaystyle C^{*}} is a continuous function.[15]

It is also possible to generalize Berge's theorem to non-compact set-valued correspondences if the objective function is K-inf-compact.[16]

Examples [edit]

Consider a utility maximization problem where a consumer makes a choice from their budget set. Translating from the notation above to the standard consumer theory notation,

Then,

Proofs in general equilibrium theory often apply the Brouwer or Kakutani fixed-point theorems to the consumer's demand, which require compactness and continuity, and the maximum theorem provides the sufficient conditions to do so.

See also [edit]

  • Envelope theorem
  • Brouwer fixed point theorem
  • Kakutani fixed point theorem for correspondences

Notes [edit]

  1. ^ Ok, Efe (2007). Real Analysis with Economics Applications . Princeton University Press. p. 306. ISBN978-0-691-11768-3.
  2. ^ The original reference is the Maximum Theorem in Chapter 6, Section 3 Claude Berge (1963). Topological Spaces. Oliver and Boyd. p. 116. Famously, or perhaps infamously, Berge only considers Hausdorff topological spaces and only allows those compact sets which are themselves Hausdorff spaces. He also requires that upper hemicontinuous correspondences be compact-valued. These properties have been clarified and disaggregated in later literature.
  3. ^ Compare with Theorem 17.31 in Charalambos D. Aliprantis; Kim C. Border (2006). Infinite Dimensional Analysis: A Hitchhiker's Guide . Springer. pp. 570. ISBN9783540295860. This is given for arbitrary topological spaces. They also consider the possibility that f {\displaystyle f} may only be defined on the graph of C {\displaystyle C} .
  4. ^ Compare with Theorem 3.5 in Shouchuan Hu; Nikolas S. Papageorgiou (1997). Handbook of Multivalued Analysis. Vol. 1: Theory. Springer-Science + Business Media, B. V. p. 84. They consider the case that Θ {\displaystyle \Theta } and X {\displaystyle X} are Hausdorff spaces.
  5. ^ Theorem 3.6 in Beavis, Brian; Dobbs, Ian (1990). Optimization and Stability Theory for Economic Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press. pp. 83–84. ISBN0-521-33605-8.
  6. ^ Compare with Theorem 7 in Chapter 6, Section 1 of Claude Berge (1963). Topological Spaces. Oliver and Boyd. p. 112. Berge assumes that the underlying spaces are Hausdorff and employs this property for X {\displaystyle X} (but not for C {\displaystyle C} ) in his proof.
  7. ^ Compare with Proposition 2.46 in Shouchuan Hu; Nikolas S. Papageorgiou (1997). Handbook of Multivalued Analysis. Vol. 1: Theory. Springer-Science + Business Media, B. V. p. 53. They assume implicitly that Θ {\displaystyle \Theta } and X {\displaystyle X} are Hausdorff spaces, but their proof is general.
  8. ^ Compare with Corollary 17.18 in Charalambos D. Aliprantis; Kim C. Border (2006). Infinite Dimensional Analysis: A Hitchhiker's Guide . Springer. pp. 564. ISBN9783540295860. This is given for arbitrary topological spaces, but the proof relies on the machinery of topological nets.
  9. ^ Compare with Theorem 2 in Chapter 6, Section 3 of Claude Berge (1963). Topological Spaces. Oliver and Boyd. p. 116. Berge's argument is essentially the one presented here, but he again uses auxiliary results proven with the assumptions that the underlying spaces are Hausdorff.
  10. ^ Compare with Proposition 3.1 in Shouchuan Hu; Nikolas S. Papageorgiou (1997). Handbook of Multivalued Analysis. Vol. 1: Theory. Springer-Science + Business Media, B. V. p. 82. They work exclusively with Hausdorff spaces, and their proof again relies on topological nets. Their result also allows for f {\displaystyle f} to take on the values ± {\displaystyle \pm \infty } .
  11. ^ Compare with Lemma 17.30 in Charalambos D. Aliprantis; Kim C. Border (2006). Infinite Dimensional Analysis: A Hitchhiker's Guide . Springer. pp. 569. ISBN9783540295860. They consider arbitrary topological spaces, and use an argument based on topological nets.
  12. ^ Compare with Theorem 1 in Chapter 6, Section 3 of Claude Berge (1963). Topological Spaces. Oliver and Boyd. p. 115. The argument presented here is essentially his.
  13. ^ Compare with Proposition 3.3 in Shouchuan Hu; Nikolas S. Papageorgiou (1997). Handbook of Multivalued Analysis. Vol. 1: Theory. Springer-Science + Business Media, B. V. p. 83. They work exclusively with Hausdorff spaces, and their proof again relies on topological nets. Their result also allows for f {\displaystyle f} to take on the values ± {\displaystyle \pm \infty } .
  14. ^ Compare with Lemma 17.29 in Charalambos D. Aliprantis; Kim C. Border (2006). Infinite Dimensional Analysis: A Hitchhiker's Guide . Springer. pp. 569. ISBN9783540295860. They consider arbitrary topological spaces and use an argument involving topological nets.
  15. ^ Sundaram, Rangarajan K. (1996). A First Course in Optimization Theory . Cambridge University Press. p. 239. ISBN0-521-49770-1.
  16. ^ Theorem 1.2 in Feinberg, Eugene A.; Kasyanov, Pavlo O.; Zadoianchuk, Nina V. (January 2013). "Berge's theorem for noncompact image sets". Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications. 397 (1): 255–259. arXiv:1203.1340. doi:10.1016/j.jmaa.2012.07.051. S2CID 8603060.

References [edit]

  • Claude Berge (1963). Topological Spaces. Oliver and Boyd. pp. 115–117.
  • Charalambos D. Aliprantis; Kim C. Border (2006). Infinite Dimensional Analysis: A Hitchhiker's Guide . Springer. pp. 569-571. ISBN9783540295860.
  • Shouchuan Hu; Nikolas S. Papageorgiou (1997). Handbook of Multivalued Analysis. Vol. 1: Theory. Springer-Science + Business Media, B. V. pp. 82–89.

sagesuaing.blogspot.com

Source: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Maximum_theorem

0 Response to "Prove That the Max of Two Continuous Functions is Continuous Topology"

Post a Comment

Iklan Atas Artikel

Iklan Tengah Artikel 1

Iklan Tengah Artikel 2

Iklan Bawah Artikel